The Oil Market As An Oligopoly

Table of Contents

Introduction

Original: We are excited to start this new project

Paraphrased: We are thrilled to launch this fresh endeavor.

Oil supply outside the Oligopoly

An examination of previous research on the subject.

Conclusion/Recommendation

Citing sources

This topic considers the oil markets as an Oligopoly with some competition. Egypt, Oman Mexico, Malaysia, Norway and all OPEC member countries are assumed to be the oligopoly. The remaining oil producers are included within a fringe in which the price of oil is assumed to be determined exogenously. We specify the outcomes of different levels of collusion between the members of an oligopoly. We also study intermediate cases such as full or partial cooperation in OPEC with no cooperation between OPEC members.

IntroductionThe future growth of oil prices will be determined by how effectively OPEC members can organize their production choices and whether OPEC is successful in collaborating alongside other oil producers. In addition to those in OPEC, many other nations will also suffer large losses in revenue due to a drop in oil costs. This has clearly influenced the decision of some countries to consult OPEC when asked to do so in order to support OPEC’s market control. The benefits of being an unrestricted market participant must be considered by every market operator. Berger Bjerkholt & Olsen, 1987, examines the benefits of collaboration with OPEC as seen from Mexico and Norway’s perspective. The study began with a basic incomplete market balance (WOM) and then focused on the question of participation by using various presumptions regarding exogenous supplies of oil from different locations. These re-enactments were not based on formal behaviour relations in the oil market. While it could be questioned if a formal cartel show would fit the clearly complicated relations in unrefined crude oil markets around the world, we still believe that an official investigation is helpful to understanding current and future market developments.

This paper views oil advertising as a oligopoly. Berger and co.’s thinking is predictable. (operation. Cit) We accept that Egypt is well on its way to collaborating with OPEC, as are Oman, Mexico and Malaysia. This oligopoly includes all OPEC nations and also these countries. The oil-producing nations that are not OPEC members are also included into an oligopoly which, presumably, takes oil price increases as exogenous. Consider the effects of shifting levels of agreement in an oligopoly. The oligopoly’s participation has been broken down to the point of being outrageous.

The oligopoly can also organize its generation in such a way as to maximize the benefits for all members. We also consider middle-cases, for instance, complete or insufficient participation within OPEC. The net petroleum interest which the oligopoly confronts is generally constant with demand and production relations in the model WOM. Restriction theoretical framework. In the first place, in the WOM model, capacity limitations of oligopoly players are maintained, pushing marginal minor costs up as demand or production grows. In addition, the model’s purest version of its impact on substitutability was the imminence of a fence. On the whole, it can be said that the model is a little more negative in its cost estimations over the short-to-medium term, while being a bit more optimistic over the longer run. In its present form, all limit points are exogenous. This is clearly unacceptable for a long-term examination. We want to localize generation limitations in a later version of our model. For this to work, it is best to use the long-run cost capacities. These include costs for extending limits. The oligopoly game can be displayed as a 2-arranged diversion. In the first stage, capacity limits are determined by balancing a non-cooperative games. The second phase can be shown in a similar way to the one depicted in the following, i.e. With exogenous limits. The limit you select in the first stage of the game will determine the outcome in the second, and consequently the result for each player. The decision made in the main stage about the capacity will have an impact on the outcome of the game in the next stage and thus the reward for every player. The amount of collusion that occurs in the second game stage will affect the relationship between capacity and payoffs.

The addition to the world’s oil demand (outside China and the East Bloc) is determined by: D=D (P,Zd). P is the dollar price of oil and Zd represents a vector that includes exogenous factors such as income levels and exchange rates in different nations. The WOM model is used to calculate the total oil demand. The total oil demand in three WOM locations, namely the USA, what’s left of OECD countries, and LDC’s, is D. A model that is based on observational evidence must be able separate oil market factors’ reactions to shocks in the oil industry from their responses to global financial developments. In order to meet our goal, we have selected worldwide financial indicators that are both reliable and catch the highlights of global business cycles.

Oil Outside OligopolyThe Supply Condition is Adjusted in the Following Route: In the Show WOM a Sub Model is Indicate for the Gathering of Makers outside OPEC. This submodel is used to identify oil production in these nations as different oil stores. Investigation and extraction from these oil stores depend on (normal) crude oil prices. This sub-model is repeated for different years (up to 2000) based on assumptions of oil costs and other factors. It produces non-OPEC supplies by changing the mix of factors. Total world supplies from outside oligopoly nations are shown as S=S (P, Zs). In Zs there is an inclination to the period. The time-drift is used to represent a gradual decline in oil supply at a constant price, due to depletion.

OPEC cartel – side payments This model is not far from an aggressive agreement, mainly because of the large number of oligopoly experts working on the market. Saudi Arabia is the only nation with a minimal cost below 90 percent. Saudi Arabia has minimal costs that are 68 percent the cost of oil, while Ecuador has more than 99. The projections for 2000 and 2010 indicate that solid increases are sought. Even high-cost nations are able to create over 97 percent. Oil costs are a major factor, as they have risen from 32.70 US$/barrel to 86.90 US$/barrel since 2000. The calculations are based on the assumption that oil prices will rise. However, this is not true. In the reenactment below, we have allowed 13 OPEC oligopolies in a cartel to work together. As per segment 6.2, we have divided the segments into two. NOPEC states continue to act in the same way as Cournot-oligopolies. The main difference from the Cournot pure case is the fact that OPEC lowers the production in the base-year and so the oil price builds. OPEC nations halved their production in 1986. This hypothetical model assigns creation based on the cost limit. All nations should be able to meet the minimum cost. The emotional impact of peripheral costs is contrasted to the reproduction of oligopoly; the minimal cost that OPEC nations pay on a regular basis only represents 31 percent the cost for oil. The minor cost for OPEC in 2000 and 2010 was still below the oil price (25 and 20% of the cost, respectively). Nevertheless, marginal costs and price both increase, which implies a corresponding rise in production. The inverse L state for these nations will result in high limits even at direct marginal costs. Limit usage is 87 % in 2000 and 98 % in 2010. All NOPEC countries. In 2000 and 2010, they delivered near their potential. Oman has low-cost oilfields that are already producing the limit of their ability in 2010. In 2000, all nations in NOPEC were nearing 100 percent limit and will reach 100 percent by 2010. These nations’ marginal costs are very close to oil prices, with the exception of Mexico, where small expenses represent 90% of their cost. In this simulation, the oil price is 40 percent higher than the pure oligopoly scenario.

Literature ReviewOil, in particular demand shocks, contributed to the acceleration and decline of oil’s price in mid-2015. As can be seen from the top-right plot, the global production has been disintegrating. This is likely due to the continued extension of unpredictability in shale gas creation. “Understanding The Decline In The Price Of Oil Since June 2014. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 3, 131-158. The desire for overabundance in oil markets was likely influenced by a few factors: the return to production at oil fields in Iraq, Libya and other countries after the threat from radicals ended, a greater certainty on the market that the expansion of shale gas production would continue despite the recent price decline, and OPEC’s reluctance to reduce its production. Baumeister and Hamilton (2015) have recognized the importance of providing a possible prior on the oil-free market activity volatility. The study shows that the distribution of oil demand and supply elasticities can be used to restrict the design of models. Around 35 percent of oil price variations can be explained by global demand shocks, as opposed to Kilian’s (2009) 8 percent and Baumeister and Hamilton’s (2015b) 4 percent. IP is used in a similar way to Aastveit et al. The study by (2015) examines the impact of the demand for oil from developing and cutting-edge economies on the price.

During the recent years, coordination efforts were made and some agreements tacitly reached between OPEC-members and non OPEC oil producers. These contacts are hard to describe in a formal way, but the fact that they exist should be enough to generate interest in the current model. The cartel’s market power is significantly increased when the five NOPEC nations are included. The cartel uses this to its advantage. In the base year the total production of the 18 nations is reduced by a third compared to an oligopoly, and 18 percent compared the OPEC cartel solution. In the base period, the price of a barrel is 22.40 US$. This is an increase by 78 percent over the oligopoly scenario. The monopoly of the cartel is reduced in both OPEC and the oligopoly simulations. This can be seen in the fact the oil price in 2010 is not much higher than it was in the Cournot case. In the current simulation, output is cut by 15 per cent in 2010, but oil prices are raised 40 percent that same year.

Conclusion/RecommendationThe motivation behind this topic is to display a structure for breaking down different sorts of strategic behaviour and collusive behaviour in the crude oil market. The investigation was a preliminary one and should not be taken as an actual demonstration of any strategic model. Oil supply shocks are responsible for about half of the oil price fluctuations during business cycles, while global demand shocks make up 30%. Dropping oil prices due to oil supply shocks can boost the economic activity of advanced economies and depress that of emerging economies.

References1. Osborne, D.K. (1976): “Cartel problems. American economics review, 66.

2. Baumeister, C. “Understanding The Decline In The Price Of Oil Since June 2014”. The Association of Environmental and Resource Economists published an article in the Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 3 (1), which discussed the implications of 131-158.

3. Kilian, L. (2009). Not All Oil Price Awakenings Are the Same: Disentangling demand and supply shocks in Crude Oil Market. The American Economic Review’s 99th volume, 3rd edition.

4. Baumeister, C. & J. D. Hamilton (2015). “Structural interpretation of vector autoregressions with incomplete identification: Revisiting oil supply and demand shocks.” Manuscript from the University of Notre Dame UCSD.”

5. Aastveit K. A. H. C. Bjrnland L. A. Thorsrud 2015 What drives oil prices? Emerging versus Developed Economies. The Journal of Applied Econometrics published an article in its 30th volume, 7th issue, discussing topics ranging from 1013 to 1028.

6. Berger, K. and O. Bjerkholt (1987): What are the options available to non-OPEC producers? Discussion Paper No. Discussion Paper No.

7. Newbery, D., 1981: “Oil Prices, Cartels and the Problem of Dynamic Inconsistency.” Economic Journal, vol. 91, no. 617-646

Author

  • valentinomcintyre

    Valentino McIntyre is a 39-year-old blogger and schoolteacher from the United States. He is a dedicated father and husband and has been married to his wife for over 10 years. Valentino has a vast amount of experience in the education field, having worked as a teacher for over 15 years. He is a prolific writer and has been blogging for over 10 years. His blog is a source of information and inspiration for parents and educators.